Tuesday, May 26, 2020

Wages, prices, and employment in a Keynesian long run

Stephen A. Marglin

Keywords: flexprice adjustment; fixprice adjustment; conventional wage; unlimited supplies of labor; capital widening; capital deepening; Phillips curve

Published in print:Jul 2017


Category:Research Article


Pages:360–425

Download PDF (1.7 MB)

The central question this paper addresses is the same one I explored in my joint work with Amit Bhaduri 25 years ago: under what circumstances are high wages good for employment? I extend our 1990 argument in three directions. First, instead of mark-up pricing, I model labor and product markets separately. The labor supply to the capitalist sector of the economy is assumed à la Lewis to be unlimited. Consequently the wage cannot be determined endogenously but is fixed by an extended notion of subsistence based on Smith, Ricardo, and Marx. For tractability the product market is assumed to be perfectly competitive. The second innovation is to show how disequilibrium adjustment resolves the overdetermination inherent in the model. There are three equations – aggregate demand, goods supply, and labor supply – but two unknowns – the labor–capital ratio and the real price (the inverse of the real wage). Consequently equilibrium does not even exist until we define the adjustment process. The third innovation is to distinguish capital deepening from capital widening. This is important because, ceteris paribus, wage-led growth is more likely to stimulate the economy the greater the fraction of investment devoted to capital deepening. A final section of the paper shows that US data on employment and inflation since the 1950s are consistent with the theory developed in this paper.



Full Text

1 INTRODUCTION

Are high wages good for employment? Does higher employment lead to more inflation? When do higher prices mean stagflation? This essay lays out and tests a new framework for assessing the relationship between prices and wages on the one hand and output and employment on the other. I build on my work with Amit Bhaduri of a quarter of a century ago (Marglin and Bhaduri 1990; Bhaduri and Marglin 1990). The central innovation of this joint work was to question the conventional wisdom of left-leaning political economy that higher wages are always good for employment and output. Higher wages, Bhaduri and I argued, may decrease aggregate demand through a negative impact on investment demand. Here, I expand the argument by focusing on the differences in the relationship between wages and employment under different adjustment regimes. The expanded model allows me to examine supply and demand shocks under different dynamic assumptions, and to test the Keynesian idea that aggregate demand matters against data on employment and inflation. I also offer an argument about how different types of investment respond to profitability and capacity utilization, an argument intended to clarify the impact of wages on aggregate demand via the investment channel.

From a mainstream point of view, the entire tradition in which Bhaduri and I situated our work – the tradition in which aggregate demand matters in the long run as well as in the short run – was conceived in error. The process of consolidating the Keynesian revolution made a role for aggregate demand contingent on one form or another of market imperfection or friction, and the resulting sand in the wheels was supposed to operate only in the short term. By the late 1960s, when the neoclassical counter-revolution had begun in earnest, the Keynesians had already abandoned the long run to the neoclassicals. Robert Solow's 1956 essay was widely understood to have demonstrated the irrelevance of aggregate demand, even though the ‘demonstration,’ as Solow himself recognized (ibid., p. 91), is simply an assumption.

The counter-revolution, led by Milton Friedman (1968) and Edmund Phelps (1968), delivered the knock-out punch – or so it was believed. A positive relationship between employment and inflation, enshrined in the Phillips curve (Phillips 1958), was understood by Keynesians to reflect the operation of aggregate demand. The counter-revolutionaries dismissed the Phillips curve as the result of misperceptions that would necessarily disappear as agents developed more sophistication about the economy. The implication was that demand cannot matter in the long run. Indeed, Friedman and Phelps predicted that periods of high inflation would not be accompanied by higher economic activity. In the long run there is no Phillips curve, no trade-off between economic activity and price stability. In this perspective raising money wages is necessarily an exercise in futility: higher wages can mean only higher inflation, with no impact on employment and output. The classical dichotomy with a vengeance!

Some years later, Robert Lucas (1981, p. 560) claimed that experience had borne out the Friedman–Phelps predictions:


The central forecast to which their [Friedman and Phelps's] reasoning led was a conditional one, to the effect that a high-inflation decade should not have less unemployment on average than a low-inflation decade. We got the high inflation decade, and with it as clear-cut an experimental discrimination as macroeconomics is ever likely to see, and Friedman and Phelps were right. It really is as simple as that.We have a lot more data available today than Lucas had at his disposal in 1981. And the data do appear to bear out the prediction that there is no relationship between employment and inflation. Figure 1 plots the data over more than half a century. Analysing these data, economists have found, if anything, a negative relationship between real economic activity and inflation. Cross-sectional studies by Stanley Fischer (1993), Robert Barro (1996), and others have found a significant negative correlation between growth and inflation, but their results are dominated by high inflation rates, where negative supply-side effects plausibly dominate. More striking are the findings of Moshin Khan and Abdelhak Senhadji (2001), who separate poor and rich countries and find that for the rich countries the threshold above which inflation is associated with lower GDP growth is only 1–3 percent per year.


Figure 1Employment vs inflation, 1956–2011

Citation: 5, 3;10.4337/roke.2017.03.04

None of this should surprise us. Once it has been determined that demand does not matter in the long run, it makes sense to treat all observations symmetrically and look for supply-side effects.

Appearances notwithstanding, we can make sense of the data in terms of a Phillips curve along which movements reflect demand shocks but which is itself moved by supply shocks, as Robert Gordon (1984; 2013) and others have argued. Demand shocks result in the standard Phillips result, a positive relationship between employment and inflation. As we shall see, supply shocks are more complicated.

The key to finding order in the randomness of Figure 1 is to filter the data in two ways. Not only must we separate demand and supply shocks, we must also sort out wage shocks (which affect employment and wages through their effect on labor supply) from price shocks (which operate through goods supply on employment and output). This done, there were, I shall argue, two periods in which wage pressure exerted a strong influence on the positive Phillips-curve relationship: in the late 1960s and early 1970s upward pressure on wages displaced the relationship between employment and inflation upwards, and in the mid 1990s downward pressure on wages displaced the relationship downwards. This suggests that high(er) wages have historically exerted a negative influence on the economy, but, in line with the central hypothesis put forward by Bhaduri and me 25 years ago, this result is contextual. Both instances of wage pressure took place under conditions of high employment and, presumably, high investment demand – precisely the conditions under which Bhaduri and I argued that higher wages would not improve aggregate outcomes.

This leaves open the possibility that under conditions of slack, such as characterize global capitalism since the financial crisis that inaugurated the Great Recession, the impact of higher wages would be very different from 20 or 40 years ago. Higher wages would indeed stimulate the economy.


Wage increases, transfers, and the socially determined income distribution in the USA*

Lance TaylorArmon RezaiRishabh KumarNelson Barbosa and Laura Carvalho

Keywords: wealth distributionincome distributionSAM

Published in print:Apr 2017



Category:Research Article

DOI:https://doi.org/10.4337/roke.2017.02.07Pages:259–275

Download PDF (202.5 KB)

This paper is based on a social accounting matrix (SAM) which incorporates the size distribution of income based on data from the BEA national accounts, the widely discussed 2012 CBO distribution study, and BLS consumer surveys. Sources and uses of incomes are disaggregated by household groups including the top 1 percent. Their importance (including saving rates) differs markedly across households. The SAM reveals two transfer flows exceeding 10 percent of GDP via fiscal (broadly progressive) and financial (regressive) channels. A third major flow over time has been a ten percentage point increase in the GDP share of the top 1 percent. A simulation model is used to illustrate how ‘feasible’ modifications to tax/transfer programs and increasing low wages cannot offset the historical redistribution toward the well-to-do.

1 INTRODUCTION

In the USA there is ongoing debate about how the positions of the ‘poor’ (say, households in the bottom one or two quintiles of the size distribution of income), the ‘rich’ (the top decile or top percentile), and the ‘middle class’ (households ‘between’ these two groups) will be affected by fiscal and other initiatives such as raising the minimum wage. Feedbacks of distributive changes into macroeconomic performance are equally of interest. This paper highlights the severe limitations to reducing income inequality in the USA. In model simulations, when they are applied at politically ‘feasible’ levels, standard policy tools such as increased taxes on high income households, higher transfers to people with low incomes, and raising wages at the bottom do not reduce rich-vs-poor inequality by very much.

The basic reason is that consistent macroeconomic accounting shows that there are three income redistribution flows on the order of 10 percent of GDP. The first two are fiscal tax/transfer payments (broadly progressive) and financial transactions (regressive). The last is an increase over 2 decades by 10 percent of GDP in the share of primary incomes appropriated (some might say expropriated) by the top 1 percent of income recipients. In a macroeconomically consistent framework incorporating the size distribution of income we show that policy interventions such as those mentioned above cannot reverse this historically large and unrequited income transfer.

For ease of presentation the household size distribution is rescaled to the national income and product accounts (NIPA). It is summarized by a metric (the ‘Palma ratio’) which, as opposed to the standard Gini coefficient, emphasizes the disparity in incomes between the ‘poor’ (say, households in the bottom one or two quintiles of the size distribution of income) and the ‘rich’ (the top decile or top percentile). The ratio has trended strongly upward over time.

To trace macroeconomic and distributive linkages through, we use a simple, static demand-driven macro model based on a social accounting matrix (SAM) which enfolds meso-level data on key distributive variables (types of income including transfers received, taxes paid, consumption, saving) for swaths of the size distribution into the NIPA system. Basically, we rescaled available data to fabricate a representation of the size distribution consistent with the NIPA from the US Bureau of Economic Analysis (the BEA accounts are themselves a fabrication). The numbers provide a broad-brush representation of the distributive situation for the period 1986–2009. For the model simulations we focused on 2008, a relatively ‘representative’ year for the economy. While the distribution of income for the US economy is well known, there is less clarity on the size distribution of expenditure. As a first approximation we use less granular estimates on consumption and saving rates for most of the population. For the top decile and fractiles (top 10 percent and top 1 percent) we extend the relationship between income and saving using log-linear extrapolation. Our numbers are consistent with other estimations of the size distribution of income, such as the recent study by Alvaredo et al. (2013) and Saez and Zucman (2014). We use a Congressional Budget Office (CBO) study, itself based on administrative tax data, which captures a detailed breakdown of income across a more representative sample of households. Unlike the Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF), there is less concern in this data set regarding oversampling of wealthy households and exclusion of the Forbes 400.

We begin the presentation in Sections 24 with a review of the US size distribution in the context of the SAM, shedding light on how relatively large fiscal and financial transfer payments and unequal income flows fit into the macro system. In Section 5, we go on to simulation results, before concluding with a brief discussion in Section 6Appendix 1 briefly discusses the Republican ‘Path to Prosperity’ budget proposal in the House of Representatives. Appendix 2 reports details on how we put the accounting together and sets out the specification of the model.
The road they share: the social conflict element in Marx, Keynes and Kalecki

Pablo Gabriel Bortz

Keywords: Keynes; Kalecki; Marx; social conflict; fiscal policy; interest rate

Published in print:Oct 2017

Category:Research Article


Pages:563–575

Download PDF (100.6 KB)

https://www.elgaronline.com/view/journals/roke/5-4/roke.2017.04.06.xml

This paper sets out to find commonalities and divergences in the writings of Marx, Kalecki and Keynes regarding their analysis of social (class) conflict in capitalist societies. We find evidence that shows that, contrary to a harmonious view of society, Keynes had a class stratification of society and an understanding of conflictive interests and developments compatible with that of Marx and Kalecki. The presence of political motivations as fuel for economic instability is another shared element between Kalecki and Keynes. Differences arise regarding the relative importance of the inter- and intra-class dynamic as a driver of distributive conflict, and the State's capabilities to guide or control those conflicts and their consequences.

1 INTRODUCTION

‘The class war will find me on the side of the educated bourgeoisie’, Keynes famously stated in his pamphlet ‘Am I a liberal?’ (CW IX, p. 297). 1 His political affiliations have been the object of several analyses (Skidelsky 2003; Dostaler 2007, among others). It is widely known that he rejected Marxism, and particularly Marx's theory, even though on many occasions he made use of some of Marx's concepts, such as the monetary circulation scheme. It is understood that Keynes sought to protect capitalism by changing it from within. This paper seeks to explore a different aspect of Keynes's theory, not focusing on his political actions and tastes, but on the political corollaries of his theory. We aim to understand the role of conflict and social struggle; whether it implies a harmonious view of (capitalist) society such as in the marginalist theory (as presented by Jevons or John Bates Clark, for instance); or whether it reflects a struggle, divergence and incompatibilities in the interest of the different classes of society that expresses itself in an economic behaviour full of macroeconomic consequences. We are also interested in Keynes's acknowledgement of the political obstacles faced by the policy choices implied by these theoretical corollaries, both in domestic and international affairs.

It seems natural to compare this role with the theories of the other two major economists who adopted a class stratification structure when developing their analyses of capitalism, namely Karl Marx and Michał Kalecki. Marx is known to define class struggle, or social conflict, as the engine of history. In a capitalist society, the search for higher profits through cost-cutting innovation and labour-saving investment eventually produces the opposite effect by leading to falling profit rates and accumulation crises. Giving in to this analysis, Bismarck developed what we call today a welfare state, in order to support a minimal standard of living for the working poor and the disabled, effectively sustaining a certain demand level. It would not be stretching the imagination too far to say that such appeasing policies, which seem to have got the approval of Kalecki and Keynes, would reflect a social cooperation view identifiable with the writings of these authors. 2 However, it is the contention of this paper that Kalecki's and Keynes's view and theories on the topic have more in common with Marx than a casual reading might suggest. That is not surprising for the case of Kalecki, who was himself inspired by authors such as Rosa Luxemburg and Mikhail Tugan-Baranovsky, but also in the case of Keynes, a careful reading will show that a class structure also permeates his view and analysis, with conflicting interest among and within them.

The paper is structured as follows, with the clarification that we will restrict our focus to writings referring to capitalism. Section 2 reviews the role of intra- and inter-class conflict in Marx's analysis, using it as the background or benchmark for comparison throughout the paper. Section 3 reviews Kalecki's writings on the topic under discussion, while Section 4 surveys Keynes's writings, quoting extensively in order to reflect a consistent view of the political factors, inextricably linked with class interests, involved in the description, diagnosis and policy prescriptions for the maladies of capitalist economies. Section 5 concludes.


Rethinking macroeconomic theory before the next crisis
Marc Lavoie
Keywords: potential output; financial crisis; hysteresis; DSGE models


Published in print:Jan 2018Category:Research ArticleDOI:https://doi.org/10.4337/roke.2018.01.01Pages:1–21
Download PDF (299 KB)

Flowing Text
Original Pages
Misguided economics policies relying on an unrealistic macroeconomic theory that denied the possibility of a crisis are at the origins of the global financial crisis. The goal of the present paper is to recall how the end of the Great Moderation has been interpreted by the advocates of mainstream economics, and how they have questioned their own macroeconomic theories as a consequence of what happened during and after the financial crisis. There is thus a need to reconsider most aspects of mainstream theory. In particular, the crisis has once more demonstrated that potential output is influenced by aggregate demand – a phenomenon associated with hysteresis, which also questions concepts such as the natural rate of interest and crowding-out effects.
Full Text


1 INTRODUCTION



While many countries throughout the world have faced severe financial crises over the last decades, and while the Japanese stagnation and the 1997 Asian financial crisis did induce some additional interest for the introduction of banking and finance into macroeconomic theory, it is only with the advent of the US subprime financial crisis that macroeconomic and monetary theories put forward by mainstream economists have started to be questioned. Still, there are at least two views about the role played by economic theory in generating the global financial crisis, which, depending on one's opinion, can be ascertained as having started at any of the three following times: when real-estate prices in the US started to decline in the summer of 2006; when interbank money markets first froze in Europe during the summer of 2007; or when it was announced that the Lehman Brothers investment bank declared bankruptcy on the 15th of September 2008. If we take the earliest date, then we can say that the financial crisis and its aftermath have been going on for over a decade.



Heterodox authors were criticizing mainstream economic theory in all its incarnations long before the global financial crisis. My purpose in writing this paper is not to survey these heterodox criticisms, whose value has been reinforced with the advent of the crisis, nor to assess the impact of the crisis on the future of heterodox economics. 1 Rather, the goal of the present paper is to briefly recall how the end of the Great Moderation – this 15-year period of low inflation and low variance in real growth rates in the Western world – has been interpreted by the advocates of mainstream economics: this is mainly done in Section 2. The rest of the paper is devoted to a review of a number of key issues in macroeconomic theory, examining what seems to have been changed or been questioned as a consequence of what has happened during and after the financial crisis. As a result, Section 3 will be devoted to the concept of hysteresis, which seems to have been resurrected by mainstream economists. Section 4 will deal with a number of miscellaneous issues, in particular the shape of the aggregate demand curve and the lack of a relationship between interest rates and public debt or deficit ratios. I will conclude in Section 5 with broad brush-strokes about what ought to disappear and what might disappear from macroeconomic theory. Many others, such as Stiglitz (2011; 2015) and Mendoza Bellido (2013) have done an excellent job in pursuing this kind of exercise. Here I offer my idiosyncratic thoughts, starting with the reaction of economists to the crisis.

https://www.elgaronline.com/view/journals/roke/6-1/roke.2018.01.01.xml

Have we been here before? Phases of financialization within the twentieth century in the US

Apostolos Fasianos, Diego Guevara and Christos Pierros

Keywords: financialization; monetary regimes; speculation

Published in print:Jan 2018

Category:Research Article


Pages:34–61

Download PDF (554.4 KB)

This paper explores the process of financialization from a historical perspective during the course of the twentieth century. We identify four phases of financialization: the first from the 1900s to 1933 (early financialization), the second from 1933 to 1940 (transitory phase), the third between 1945 and 1973 (de-financialization), and the fourth period picks up from the early 1970s and leads to the Great Recession (complex financialization). Our findings indicate that the main features of the current phase of financialization were already in place in the first period. We closely examine institutions within these distinct financial regimes and focus on the relative size of the financial sector, the respective regulation regime of each period, the intensity of the shareholder value orientation, as well as the level of financial innovations implemented. Although financialization is a recent term, the process is far from novel. We conclude that its effects can be studied better with reference to economic history.

1 INTRODUCTION

When did financialization start? While there is much literature on the increasing dominance of finance in the United States after 1970, little work to date has attempted to investigate whether financialization was taking place earlier. Whereas few authors consider financialization as an evolutionary process that can be traced back to pre-capitalist societies, most analysts emphasize the neoliberal period beginning in the 1980s.

Financialization, as Sawyer (2013/2014) appropriately describes it, is a process that widely varies in form and intensity across time and space. Accordingly, by utilizing empirical and qualitative analytical tools coming from different schools of thought, we identify distinct phases of financialization during the twentieth century in the US. In particular, we examine the resemblance of financialization's characteristics in the early twentieth century with those of the contemporary period, questioning whether the current phase of financialization is a vaguely different repetition of its older counterpart, as observed, for example, in the early 1900s.

To carry out our task, we divide the sample period into four distinct regimes, marked by structural breaks in the institutional setting of the economy, which affected the functioning of the financial sector. The first period of early financialization lasts from the beginning of the twentieth century up until 1933, as the New Deal agreement brought significant changes in financial regulation and policy orientation. The second period (1933–1940) reflects the transitory phase of the economy that leads to the third period, the ‘Golden Age of Capitalist Development’ (1945–1973). The crisis of 1973 heralded the end of the Golden Age. Last, we apply Dumenil and Levy's (2011) definition of neoliberalism as ‘financialized capitalism’ to link the fourth period of complex financialization with 1974–2010.

We contribute to the relevant literature by exploring financialization from a historical perspective and pointing out different varieties of financialization throughout the twentieth century in the US. While most studies focus on a few criteria to establish evidence of financialization, we employ a plethora of empirical and qualitative indicators that allow us to formulate a synthetic argument for the pace and the form of financialization in each distinct regime. We argue that financialization, characterized by an increased role for the financial sector along with higher complexity across financial objectives and institutions, is merely the current phase of a historical process that has been unfolding since the dawn of the twentieth century. In our view, the early 1930s period presents a significant resemblance to the current phase of financialization.

Financialization is associated with financial booms and busts and has a negative impact on the real production of the economy, as it results in unemployment and highlights income inequalities. History shows that the degree of financialization is a policy variable. For instance, in the postwar period, policymakers implemented a range of policy instruments (such as full employment policies of a Keynesian flavor) and enforced a strong regulatory environment in order to restrict the uncontrolled explosion of finance. The implications of our findings could point towards policies that could reverse the destabilizing effects that financialization has on society.

The paper is organized as follows: Section 2 discusses theoretical contributions with respect to financialization; Section 3 looks at the data relating to the financialization process, focusing on the importance of the US financial sector; and Section 4 provides an analysis of the course of financialization throughout the twentieth century, paying close attention to the interaction between financial innovations and the regulatory environment, as well as to the degree of shareholder value orientation in the US economy. We also scrutinize the commitment of fiscal and monetary policies to full employment and low-inflation targeting and examine whether the economic system is prone to financial collapse. The penultimate section (Section 5) summarizes our findings, which formulate and support our argument, while the last section (Section 6) concludes.


A predator–prey model to explain cycles in credit-led economies

Óscar Dejuán and Daniel Dejuán-Bitriá

Keywords: business cycles; financial instability; predator–prey models; post-Keynesian economics

Published in print:Mar 2018

Category:Research Article


Pages:159–179

Download PDF (648.9 KB)

This paper develops a predator–prey model to explain cycles in credit-led economies. The predator is the part of the financial sector that issues credit money for non-output transactions. It increases the indebtedness ratio and inflates bubbles that eventually have a negative impact on the real rate of growth (the prey). From this basis, we build a couple of models that may lead to self-contained or explosive cycles. Even in the first case, there is a risk of a financial collapse when certain variables move far away from their long-term equilibrium positions. In order to tame the cycle and avoid extreme positions, governments should ban the expansion of credit money for the purchase of assets and introduce permanent checks to risky credit.

Full Text

1 INTRODUCTION

This is a theoretical paper whose backdrop is the credit boom leading to the financial crash of 2007 and the first great recession of the twenty-first century. This crisis witnesses the ‘financial instability hypothesis’ of Minsky (1964; 1982; 1986; 1992). It also shows that the ‘originate-to-distribute model of banking,’ which characterizes our financialized economy, has accelerated the deterioration of the debt structures. Section 2 revises the key data of this process in the USA – the epicenter of the financial turmoil.

The Minskyan ‘financial instability hypothesis’ is deployed by means of a predator–prey model. This model was introduced in the natural sciences by Lotka and Volterra. Through a system of differential equations, they captured the systemic interdependency among marine species. In Volterra (1926), the higher the population of whiting (prey), the higher the food ratio and population of sharks (predator). After a certain point, the smaller population of whiting is bound to check the expansion of sharks. The traditional idea of the survival of the fittest is not always true in nature, he concluded.

Goodwin (1967) introduced the predator–prey model to explain the counter-clockwise movement in the employment rate and the labor share in income. A profit squeeze may damage the accumulation process and, therefore, the employment rate. Goodwin's model has prompted numerous extensions to the relation between distribution and accumulation. Goodwin et al. (1984) offer a survey. More recently, Arnim and Barrales (2015) have concluded that the Goodwin–Kalecki model of ‘profit squeeze’ continues to be the preferable approach to explain supply-driven cycles.

Taylor and O'Connell (1985) used a predator–prey model to formalize Minsky's hypothesis of an ongoing climate of financial fragility leading to economic crises. In a nutshell: the endogenous deterioration of the debt structure increases liquidity preference and checks productive investment.

Taylor and O'Connell (1985) was the seminal paper that encouraged post-Keynesian economists to study the dynamic competition between the real and financial sectors of the economy. 1 The new models differ mostly on the variables playing the roles of prey and predator. For Asada (2001; 2011), private debt is the predator, and income (related to capacity utilization) is the prey. In Dejuán and González-Calvet (2005), the predator is the rate of interest, while the prey is the rate of growth of real GDP. Fazzari et al. (2008) and Oreiro et al. (2013) relate the cashflow of firms (inversely related to the rate of interest) to their investment decisions. Taylor (2012) relates Minsky with Goodwin-style cycles.

Without using a proper predatory–prey model, Ryoo and Skott build a variety of stock-flow consistent models to show the relationship between the increasing leverage of firms, the capital gains resulting from the sale of stocks, and the investment decisions that depend on Tobin's q. The final effects on the real economy will depend on whether we adopt a Kaleckian view (capacity utilization closure) or a Kaldorian one (profit share closure). In the Kaldorian version, the real sector itself has an inherent tendency towards cyclical behavior (‘short cycles’), along with the cyclical forces generated by endogenous changes in financial practices (‘long waves’) (Skott 1994; Ryoo and Skott 2008; Skott and Ryoo 2008; Ryoo 2013a; 2013b). 2 Palley (1994; 2011) contrasts the long financial cycles leading to financial crashes with the traditional business cycles. Palley (2013, p. 65) states that credit-led capitalism has developed a ‘predator–prey’ mechanism.

Our paper has also been influenced by Badhuri et al. (2006) and Werner (1997; 2005; 2015). Badhuri et al. confront the real economy (from which output and profits accrue) and the virtual one that inflates bubbles and capital gains. Werner differentiates between the circuit of output transactions and the circuit of non-output transactions (assets). The first circuit is a positive-game. The second circuit is a zero-sum game where bubbles are inflated. He reinstates the ‘quantity theory of credit’ to explain asset inflation.

In our paper, the prey will be the productive sector represented by the rate of growth of real GDP. 3 Since our interest is in the impact of financial forces, we will consider an economy that is growing at the autonomous trend marked by the expansion permanent autonomous demand, with inflation controlled by the central bank. In Section 3 we combine the Keynesian–Kaleckian principle of effective demand (Keynes 1936; Kalecki 1971) and the multiplier-accelerator mechanism. This is the supermultiplier model introduced by Hicks (1950), Serrano (1995), Bortis (1997), Dejuán (2005; 2016), and Serrano and Freitas (2015).

Following Werner (1997), the predator has been identified with the financial sector when it provides credit for non-output transactions. It brings about higher indebtedness ratios and bubbles that (eventually) damage the real economy. Section 4 analyses the forces that affect creditworthiness and their influences on aggregate demand: default rate, indebtedness ratio, burden of debt, vertigo–stampede effects, wealth effects.

In Section 5 (and in the mathematical Appendix 1) we build a variety of predator–prey models leading to self-contained or explosive cycles. Even the first ones may lead to a credit crunch and a recession. This happens when the gap between the current trend of certain variables and their long-term equilibrium rate becomes too broad. Arguably, one of the main contributions of this paper is the presence of gravity centers compatible with the principle of effective demand. The expected growth of permanent demand, provided it endures long enough, is an attractor of the growth of output at full capacity (not full employment). The same rate plus the inflation target fixed by the Central Bank marks the long-term equilibrium growth of credit. In a Sraffian mood, the fundamental value of assets (discounted at the normal rate of profit) becomes a gravity center of asset inflation (Sraffa 1960).

The conclusions of the paper are summed up in Section 6. In order to tame the cycle and avoid extreme positions, governments should ban the expansion of credit money for the purchase of assets and introduce permanent checks to risky credit.

The impact of economic policy and structural change on gender employment inequality in Latin America, 

Category:Research Article


Pages:307–332

Download PDF (279.4 KB)

Latin America experienced a decline in household income inequality in the 2000s, in sharp contrast to growing inequality in other regions of the world. This has been attributed to macroeconomic policy, social spending, and increased returns to education. This paper explores this issue from a gender perspective by econometrically evaluating how changes in economic structure and policy have impacted gendered employment and unemployment rates, as well as gender inequality in these variables, using country-level panel data for a set of 18 Latin American countries between 1990 and 2010. Three variables stand out as having consistent gender-equalizing effects in the labor market: social spending, minimum wages, and public investment. Less important or consistent were the effects of external factors (such as terms of trade), economic structure, and GDP growth.



Full Text

1 INTRODUCTION

After about a decade of relatively strong economic growth, most Latin American economies are struggling to emerge from the global growth slowdown, evident since 2009, and the ripple effects of the end of the commodity price boom. From a human development perspective, this is a particularly troubling turn of economic fortunes because the boom of the early and mid 2000s, a real departure from the crises of the 1980s and the doldrums of the 1990s, was accompanied by significant declines in household income inequality across the region. This was especially noteworthy, occurring in a region that has historically been among the world's most unequal and at a time when inequality was widening globally. Though the growth slowdown in 2009 has not yet reversed the declining inequality trend of the 2000s, it may be too soon to tell if that declining trend is structural or cyclical. It is thus all the more important to understand its causes, and whether and how more challenging economic conditions may subvert the social and economic progress achieved over the last decade. 1 A number of scholars have taken up this question, focusing on both the political (the rise of left-of-center governments) and the economic (macroeconomic and social policies) as casual factors, and relying primarily on the net household Gini coefficient (post-tax and -transfer) to measure inequality (Cornia 2014; Lopez-Calva and Lustig 2010; Tsounta and Osueke 2014).

A related but as yet unevaluated question is whether gender inequality also declined in the 2000s and if so, whether the economic determinants are similar to those identified in the empirical literature on household inequality. Considering gender inequality separately from income inequality is important because income is not always equitably shared at the household level. Research on intrahousehold resource distribution identifies distinct gender differences in access to and control over resources, indicative of non-pooling of income. Gender equality is also an important development goal in itself, not least because of the association between a number of gender equality measures (for example, health, education, and employment) and higher rates of economic growth. Time series data on the gender distribution of income at the household level do not exist, so in this paper we focus on differences in economic opportunity as reflected in employment and unemployment rates. These measures of economic opportunity are important because earning an income through employment is a crucial vector for women's economic empowerment, one that has lagged behind the substantial achievements in gender equality in health and education throughout the region. Moreover, our focus on gender-specific labor market outcomes indicates whether and how changes in economic policy and structure affect more than household income, and whether these changes contribute to creating the conditions for sustainable and transformative improvements in well-being and gender equality. Taking as a guide the empirical literature exploring income inequality trends in Latin America, we econometrically evaluate how changes in economic policy and structure have impacted gendered employment and unemployment rates, using country-level panel data for a set of 18 Latin American countries between 1990 and 2010. 

America’s chilling experiment in human sacrifice

May 26, 2020 By Lynn Parramore & Jeffrey L. Spear, Institute for New Economic Thinking
- Commentary


A chilling experiment is underway in America, with plenty of unwilling human guinea pigs.

Many parts of the country are reopening for business against the warnings of medical experts, flying in the face of grim predictions of sharply rising body counts. Two-thirds of Americans fear that the restart is happening too quickly, and the President himself acknowledges that by easing restrictions, “there’ll be more death.” Yet he presses on, even as his own White House suffers a viral outbreak.

News screens flash with tallies of death and tallies of wealth: New York’s Governor Andrew Cuomo has declared that lives must be saved “whatever it costs,” insisting that for Americans the choice “between public health and the economy” is “no contest.” But he did not ask celebrity doctor Mehmet Oz, who some weeks ago expressed his view that reopening schools could give the country its “mojo back,” and perhaps “only cost us 2-3% in terms of total mortality. (2% sounds conveniently small compared to its equivalent in human lives, 6,560,000. Oz later apologized after public outrage).

Meanwhile Dan Patrick, lieutenant governor of Texas, offered his own assessment of the trade-off between capitalism and the lives of America’s senior citizens, explaining, “there are more important things than living.”


Since the days of Adam Smith, free market capitalists have held that human beings are rational actors who pursue economic gain for self-interested motives. But here is Patrick, a free marketer if there ever was one, talking about a gift-sacrifice economy model in which people – some people, at least – lay down their lives to keep the economic engines revved.

Patrick’s words reveal an unspoken truth about capitalism. For the system to work smoothly, there have always been requirements of human sacrifice — a certain portion of the population was expected to act not as self-serving homo economicus, but self-sacrificing homo communis, focused upon what benefits the collective at their own expense. If these people can’t social distance at the workplace, they are expected to show up anyway. If there isn’t enough safety equipment, they are declared essential workers who must put their lives and that of their families at risk for the greater good.

But for whom and for what is this sacrifice intended? How much dying will be figured into state budgets and gross domestic product (GDP)? When ranked by GDP, the U.S. is the wealthiest economy in the world, but is a country’s wealth something totally separate from, or even contrary to, the health and life the majority of its citizens?



Wealth v. “illth”To help us navigate these questions, it is useful turn to someone who offered potent challenges to the economic calculus of his day: John Ruskin, the 19th-century art critic-turned-political economist. He was one of the most outspoken critics of capitalism and prevailing economic ideas of the Victorian era, and his work presciently points to shortcomings that have followed us into the present day.

Ruskin questions the premises on which free market capitalism is based, returning to first principles: what is wealth? What do we value? How should we understand the relationship between people, the economy, and the state?

In his view, economies are, above all, social systems whose true end is to benefit the people, and not, as the Texan politician would have it, the other way around. Anticipating the behavioral economics of our own day, Ruskin rejected the idea advocated by such economists as John Stuart Mill that there could be a deductive science of economics based on the assumption that the human being is “a covetous machine” that when applied to actual situations could take “the social affections,” the non-rational aspects of human behavior, into account. Ruskin recognized that such a system implicitly removed the marketplace from the constraints of religion and morality that are supposed to apply to all human behavior. He compared it to an assumption that humans are essentially a skeleton with flesh, blood and consciousness as add-ons founding “an ossifiant theory of progress on this negation of a soul.”

Ruskin defined wealth quite differently from many of his contemporaries, and ours. For him, wealth is anything that supports life and health, from the supplies in your storeroom to the song in your heart: “There is no wealth but life. Life, including all its powers of love, of joy, and of admiration. That country is the richest which nourishes the greatest number of noble and happy human beings; that man is richest who, having perfected the functions of his own life to the utmost, has also the widest helpful influence, both personal, and by means of his possessions, over the lives of others.” (Unto this Last).

By that definition, America is looking increasingly impoverished. And it is not a virus which is stealing our wealth away.

Playing on the root of the word “wealth” from the Old English word “weal,” signifying health, Ruskin proposed that while wealth was anything life-supporting that could be used and enjoyed, it had a dark counterpart that he called “illth” from the Old Norse word for bad – the things that make people ill, their lives stunted and despairing, their environment polluted. Wealth cannot be produced without illth, but great fortunes have been made by extracting the means of wealth without paying the cost of illth. To take a Ruskinian example, a factory that pollutes the water it uses, fouls the air and pays its workers below what a healthy life requires will be more profitable than a business that cleans up after itself and pays a living wage, but its illth becomes a form of national debt expressed in damage to the health of others and the environment. Think of something like a toxic Superfund site.

Economists have a term for Ruskin’s concept of illth, referring to it as “negative externalities,” even though they are not external to the capitalist economic system, but intrinsic to it. The most daunting problems of the current age, environmental disaster and inequality, are fueled by illth.




The Covid-19 crisis has merely amplified trends of rising illth, of despair, sickness, and alienation, which have been on the rise for decades as globalization, money-driven politics, decimated workers’ rights, and privatization have tipped the economic balance far in favor of the very few. If we are to judge a country’s health not by GDP, which rises in the face of a massive oil spill, but according to the criteria of the World Happiness Report (WHR), which measures things like social trust and faith in institutions, America is in bad shape when it comes to the ratio of wealth to illth. Scandinavian countries top the WHR, while the U.S. ranks a dismal 19th.

According to the Columbia University study of the 2020 WHR report, the key factors that account for the relative happiness of Scandinavian countries — what makes them wealthy in Ruskin’s terms — are precisely those that have been under pressure or cut back in the U.S. since the rise of neoliberalism: “emancipation from market dependency in terms of pensions, income maintenance for the ill or disabled, and unemployment benefits” together with labor market regulation such as a high minimum wage. Of course, no one likes to pay taxes, but Scandinavian “citizens’ satisfaction with public and common goods such as health care, education, and public transportation that progressive taxation helps to fund,” meets with approval at all income levels.

Pandemics are exacerbated by illth. We can see it in communities of color where the coronavirus strikes down those whose resources and access to health care have been limited by discriminatory policies and high contact employment. We can see it in factory farms where broken supply chains have caused farmers to euthanize livestock and plow under crops while people across the country go hungry. Airlines got immediate stimulus aid in the U.S., but there has been no subsidy for the restaurant supply chain that could be diverted for distribution by food banks and favorably located restaurants thus sustaining at least some of our much-vaunted small businesses. No one has to fly, but everyone must eat.

We sense illth accumulating in the comments of Las Vegas mayor Carolyn Goodman, who, in her eagerness to get the casinos back in business, told an astonished Anderson Cooper on CNN that she would offer up the city’s workers as a “control group” in a reopening experiment. If they weren’t able to social distance, Goodman was unconcerned: “In my opinion, you have to go ahead,” she said. “Every day you get up, it’s a gamble.”

Ruskin saw the capitalists of his day as gamblers heedless of the costs they foisted onto ordinary people: “But they neither know who keeps the bank of the gambling-house, nor what other games may be played with the same cards, nor what other losses and gains, far away among the dark streets, are essentially, though invisibly, dependent upon theirs in lighted rooms.” (Unto This Last).

In other words, not only do capitalists gamble with other peoples’ lives; they are oblivious to the fact that there are other ways to arrange society, to deal the cards differently, more fairly.

Witness the post-Covid reality imagined by Governor Cuomo. Instead of focusing on what changes could better support the health and lives of ordinary people, he has called in Google CEO Eric Schmidt to head a commission to reimagine New York state with more technology permanently inserted into every dimension of civic life. A better deal for Silicon Valley, to be sure. But what is in the cards for everyone else? When educational platforms and health protocols are mapped by gigantic and unaccountable corporations, who gets lost? Surely the answer is those who can least afford it.

President Trump says that it is time to move on from the coronavirus and get on with economy. Ruskin would have recognized the deity worshipped by country’s leader, which he called the “Goddess of getting on.” Only Ruskin recognized that she tended to favor “not of everybody’s getting on – but only of somebody’s getting on,” — what he called a “vital, or rather deathful, distinction.” For capitalists, getting on post-Covid means executives working remotely while the rank and file return to the factory floor without adequate face masks, and large corporations, not public input, determines the blueprints for our lives.

The issue of worker safety does matter to Senate Majority Leader Mitch McConnell, but not because he fears that some will get sick or die, but for a potential “epidemic of litigation.” In the next pandemic relief legislation, McConnell is looking to solve the problem of worker safety by shielding corporations from lawsuits rather than supporting Centers for Disease Control (CDC) mandated regulations that would both promote safety and sort out what is and is not actionable.






The Visible Hand

Instead of Adam Smith’s Invisible Hand, Ruskin advocated a Visible Hand of reasoned management, a government which could allocate resources effectively and create stores of what citizens most needed in a crisis. In our day this need not be a literal storehouse but surge capacity. The Obama administration, for example, contracted with Halyard Health to design a machine that could turn out 1.5 million N95 masks per day. They were ready to build the machine in 2018 when the Trump administration cancelled the program.

In Ruskin’s view, the Visible Hand was the guardian of the lives of the citizens, especially the poor, whose health and lives were their essential property. Ruskin actually defined an economy as the wise management of labor, applying labor, carefully preserving what it produces, and wisely distributing those products. A country’s wealth is in the people’s strength and health, not their illness and death.

Ruskin’s concepts of wealth and illth help us understand the centrality of ethics and responsibility to economic activity, and how economies are not an assemblage of atomistic human units but whole systems of people interacting, where the activities of some impact the lives of all. His work indicates the need for a whole systems approach to a crisis in which what happens on the beaches of Georgia impacts a nursing home in North Carolina, and visitors to New York City or New Orleans can carry the infection home. The decisions of one business in a complex international supply chain can impact the fate of millions.

In unregulated capitalism, Ruskin sussed out what Sigmund Freud might have recognized as the death drive. Decisions about the economy, he held, must be informed by the essential biologic basis of life itself: “The real science of political economy, which has yet to be distinguished from the bastard science, as medicine from witchcraft, and astronomy from astrology, is that which teaches nations to desire and labour for the things that lead to life; and which teaches them to scorn and destroy the things that lead to destruction” (Unto This Last).

The Covid crisis has exposed contradictions in market and America First ideology. Without federal aid to state and local governments, essential personnel are being laid off even as we declare them heroes. Employer based insurance is failing, but few American politicians are willing to fully embrace single payer insurance. Meat plant workers are declared essential, but still subject to deportation, as if famed Revolutionary patriot Nathan Hale had said, “I only regret that you have but one life to give for my country.”

Ultimately, the most dangerous pestilence that threatens the country is not a packet of RNA called Covid-19 but an economic and political system that does not value true wealth, and promotes the life of the few while condemning the many to literal sickness unto death.
THE CANADIAN MILITARY IS OCCUPYING CONDEMNED NURSING HOMES 
IN ONTARIO AND QUEBEC THAT WERE ABANDONED WHEN THE COVID-19

PRIVATE NURSING HOMES & LONG TERM CARE FACILITIES
AUSTERITY CUTS TO BUDGETS, CONTRACTING OUT, ABUSE OF TEMPORARY FOREIGN WORKERS, PROFITEERING OF LACK OF PATIENT CARE

DOUG FORD PREMIER OF ONT IS OUTRAGED AFTER MILITARY REPORT DESCRIBES CONDITIONS IN NURSING HOMES IT IS OCCUPYING TO CLEAN, DISINFECT AND CARE FOR PATIENTS

NO COMMENT ON POSSIBLE CRIMINAL CHARGES

FORD BACK PEDALS ON FULL NATIONALIZATION OF NURSING HOMES SAYING NOT FAIR TO PAINT THEM ALL WITH THE SAME BRUSH, OH PULLLLLLEEEEAAASSSEEE
\

Trump Golfs While More Americans Die
While the U.S. pandemic death toll approaches 100,000, the president left the White House for one of his personal golf courses
By
PETER WADE



President Trump, who has faced mounting criticism for his administration’s mishandling of the coronavirus crisis and his lack of empathy throughout, decided to leave the White House on Saturday to play golf.

According to several reports, today’s trip to the Trump National Golf Club in Sterling, Virginia, is likely his first outing to one of his private golf courses since early March. However, during the two “working weekends” the president spent at Camp David in May, it is unknown whether or not he played golf.

Trump going golfing is consistent with his reopen theme that he’s been pushing of late, but it still shows a tone-deafness and a lack of empathy. The U.S. pandemic death toll is approaching 100,000, and on top of that it’s Memorial Day weekend, a solemn occasion meant for tributes to Americans lost at war.

Trump’s work ethic hypocrisy is also on display here. Months before he would announce his candidacy for president of the United States, Trump was in full birther mode as he made several rounds on various cable news programs and talk shows attempting to delegitimize America’s first black president, Barack Obama. But when he took a pause from his factless racist attacks, he’d instead take issue with Obama’s penchant for hitting the links.

And of course, this wouldn’t be a Trump controversy without the “there’s always a tweet” meme because astonishingly, there always is.

In October of 2014, Trump tweeted that Obama was being derelict in his duties as a sitting president because he was golfing, writing, “Can you believe that, with all of the problems and difficulties facing the U.S., President Obama spent the day playing golf. Worse than Carter.”


Can you believe that,with all of the problems and difficulties facing the U.S., President Obama spent the day playing golf.Worse than Carter
— Donald J. Trump (@realDonaldTrump) October 14, 2014

And then again that same month Trump bashed Obama. But this time it wasn’t only about the former president golfing but golfing during a health crisis. You can’t make this stuff up.

“President Obama has a major meeting on the NYC Ebola outbreak, with people flying in from all over the country, but decided to play golf!” Trump tweeted.


President Obama has a major meeting on the N.Y.C. Ebola outbreak, with people flying in from all over the country, but decided to play golf!
— Donald J. Trump (@realDonaldTrump) October 24, 2014

Trump, as a phone-in guest on Fox News in 2014, spoke about Obama playing golf when, according to CNN’s Andrew Kaczynski, at the time there were two Ebola cases in the U.S.

“When you’re president, you sorta say, ‘I’m gonna give [golf] up for a couple of years and really focus on the job,’” Trump said. “It sends the wrong signal.”

Trump is golfing today.
In 2014 on Fox and Friends he criticized Obama for golfing when there were *two cases* of Ebola in the United States saying, "it sends the wrong signal" and he should have given up golf as president "to really focus on the job." https://t.co/br8jLwVLts pic.twitter.com/Jmh5CSt2mp
— andrew kaczynski🤔 (@KFILE) May 23, 2020


And in 2016, then-candidate Trump said, “I’m going to be working for you. I’m not going to have time to go play golf.”

Aerial photos capture extent of Michigan's disastrous dam failures


By Chaffin Mitchell, AccuWeather staff writer

& Mark Puleo, AccuWeather staff writer

Updated May. 22, 2020 10:48 AM


Severe flash flooding in Midland, Michigan, triggered a flood emergency declaration on May 20. Floodwaters invaded homes, farmland and many roads.

Residents in central Michigan on Thursday began returning to water-logged homes and assessing the scope of damage left by what Gov. Gretchen Whitmer described as a "500-year" flooding event. The disaster began unfolding on Tuesday after a long period of heavy rain caused rivers to swell beyond anything seen before, which resulted in two dams failing.

By Wednesday night, nearly 11,000 people in Midland had been evacuated in less than 12 hours, city officials pointed out. They also called attention to a remarkable outcome from the rapid evacuations: There were no major injuries or deaths reported during the disaster.

Whitmer visited the area on Wednesday to assess the damage left after the failures of the Edenville Dam and the Sanford Dam in Midland County


Damages are seen on one of two North M-30 bridges on Wednesday, May 20, 2020 in Edenville, Michigan. (AP Photo/Carlos Osorio)

"I think, like everyone, it was hard to believe we're in the midst of a 100-year crisis, a global pandemic and we're also dealing with a flooding event that looks to be the worse in 500 years," Gov. Whitmer said.

Inspections to roadways and bridges also began on Thursday, with city officials urging residents to stay off parkways like the Currie Bridge until experts can examine its structural safety.

Even as floodwaters began to recede on Thursday, a flood warning was enacted for the day with water levels remaining far above the flood stage. The Tittabawassee River peaked at a record crest of 35.05 feet, recorded by the National Weather Service (NWS) at 4:30 p.m. on Wednesday. The previous record of 33.9 feet stood since 1986.



Currie Bridge will need to be inspected and confirmed as structurally sound before reopened for use. Please DO NOT walk across it (barricades are still up for cars). https://t.co/o9RWE78gPG— City of Midland, MI (@CityofMidlandMI) May 21, 2020

As of Thursday night, the river was had dropped below 30 feet. In comparison, the flood stage is 24 feet and major flooding occurs when waters rise to 28 feet, according to the NWS.

Gov. Whitmer warned that the flooding could inundate parts of downtown Midland with as much as 9 feet of water. A flash flood emergency was in effect for areas downstream from the dams, including Midland City and Freeland Michigan. The flooding was so bad it was deemed 'catastrophic' by the NWS on Wednesday morning.



1/5


Aerial photos taken on May 21 capture the extensive damage in Midland, Michigan, left behind by the week's destructive flooding. (Satellite image ©2020 Maxar Technologies.)

AccuWeather National Reporter Blake Naftel was on the ground just south of Midland and described the situation as "rapidly-evolving" as the floodwaters continued rising on Wednesday. Aerial footage captured on Tuesday showed the raging waters completely overwhelming the Edenville Dam.

"Extremely dangerous flooding is ongoing along the Tittabawassee River in Midland County due to catastrophic failures at the Edenville and Sanford dams," the NWS wrote. "A Flood Warning is in effect, and anyone near the river should seek higher ground immediately, avoid driving into flood waters, and continue to heed evacuation orders given by local authorities. Life-threatening flooding continues today."


Waters overflow the Tittabawassee River, Wednesday, May 20, 2020, in Midland, Michigan. (AP Photo/Carlos Osorio)

The Edenville Dam is located about 30 miles inland from the Saginaw Bay of Lake Huron. Over 80,000 people live in Midland County.

A leading expert who has been studying and inspecting dams and levees for more than 50 years, Tom Wolff, said it is not clear if the breach was due to overtopping, or a break just before overtopping after viewing the video showing the initial break.


The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) revoked the Edenville Dam’s license for power generation in 2018 after numerous violations and longstanding concerns that the dam could not withstand a significant flood. The commission notified the dam's previous owner as far back as 1999 that it needed to increase capacity the dam's spillways, according to Detroit News.

According to Wolff, there are thousands of old and or poorly maintained dams in the US.

"American Society of State Dam Safety Officials (ASDSO) estimates more than 2,170 at-risk dams in the high hazard category. High hazard refers to consequences that include potential loss of life. So there are similar situations all around the US, and it is just a matter of when and where there is a very rare, but very large storm event that leads to overtopping and destructive erosion, or other types of failure,” Wolff said.


Wolff stressed that the public needs to be aware of where such conditions exist, and importantly in the absence of repair, mapping of what areas would flood in the event of a breach.

Concerns among residents and environmentalists grew about the potential of widespread toxic contamination after floodwaters mixed with containment ponds at the vast Dow chemical plant.

According to the Midland County Roads Commission, every bridge crossing the Tittabawassee River is closed as of 10 a.m., local time, on Wednesday.

"Many roads are under water," the MCRC said on Twitter. "Please DO NOT attempt to use roadways that are under water."


Michigan State officers return as the Tittabawassee River overflows, Wednesday, May 20, 2020, in Midland, Michigan. (AP Photo/Carlos Osorio)

Midland County emergency management told people in Midland City, Michigan, who are located west of Eastman and south of US 10, to evacuate immediately on Tuesday afternoon, according to NBC25.

A slow-moving storm doused Michigan with heavy rains over the period of several days, triggering fear of imminent dam failure and flood warnings across the state.

At least two rivers in mid-Michigan, the Tittabawassee River in Midland and the Rifle River near Sterling, reached their major flood stage on Tuesday afternoon, sending dams past their limits.

The Tittabawassee Fire and Rescue rescued the driver of a pickup truck after the vehicle was swept away while trying to drive on a flooded roadway on Tuesday, according to WNEM.


Photos shared by the Michigan State Police depict the rush of floodwaters from the broken dam wreaking havoc. (Twitter/@MSPBayRegion)

“A very slowly moving storm system and cold front pushing through the Midwest has produced anywhere from 3 to 8 inches (100 to 200 mm) of rainfall in just the past week from the western Great Lakes through northern Indiana and into southern Missouri,” AccuWeather Senior Meteorologist Jack Boston said.

Edenville Township residents along Sanford and Wixom lakes northwest of Midland were urged to evacuate their homes prior to the Edenville Dam burst. They were advised to make arrangements to stay elsewhere through Wednesday. Shelters have been set up at schools in the area.

Officials in Arenac County and Gladwin County, Michigan, also urged residents to evacuate ahead of the failure due to the possible dam breach from flash flooding along the Tittabawassee and Cedar rivers.


Edenville Dam at south end of Wixom Lake in Gladwin County, Michigan 7AM #miwx @LiveStormsMedia @Ginger_Zee @spann @CEaslickWNEM @C_Burkhart @NWSGaylord @NWSDetroit pic.twitter.com/oQKS5jvHr3— CJ Postal (@CJPostal) May 19, 2020

The Tittabawassee Township Department of Public Works asked Tittabawassee Township residents on Wednesday afternoon to reduce personal water usage and said water use may result in sewage backup to homes and businesses.

Naftel was in Midland on Wednesday morning, interviewing residents of the area and capturing the flooding devastation.

“I don’t even know what to think. It’s so crazy to see how much water is coming in, we were lucky to be on top of the crest of the hill so it's staying away from our home but we’ve got a fish or something trying to swim across,” one resident told Naftel.

Floodwaters have reached homes and covered streets in the areas, leaving some properties completely overtaken.


Footage captured by AccuWeather National Reporter Blake Naftel shows floodwaters completely covering properties, reaching houses and blanketing roads.

As floodwaters continued rising, threatening to cut off road access, emergency personnel warned citizens about the potential dangers of flooding and to find alternative routes if met with road closures.

Officials with Bay County Road Commission said the county is experiencing water over roads in some areas and water issues with draining. The commission is in the process of working on a map of roads closed and water over the road, according to the commission’s Facebook post.

With all the rain we are getting, the river is rising and roads may be underwater. If you see water over the road, please do not attempt to drive thru it. Find an alternate route. Also, We are also aware there are water issues with draining. We just received a very large amount of rain and it has no where to go. Please be patient over the next couple days,” the post reads, MLive reports.


Dan Dionne looks over his former deck outside his home, Wednesday, May 20, 2020, in Edenville, Michigan. (AP Photo/Carlos Osorio)

Around 1 a.m. Tuesday, the Saginaw County Emergency Management Team reported that an Edenville Dam failure in Midland could impact residents along the Tittabawassee River in Tittabawassee and Saginaw townships.

Midland County Emergency Management stated that the Edenville and Sanford dams are “structurally sound but spilling floodwaters” as of around 3 a.m. Tuesday, according to MLive.

Later on Tuesday, Midland County Emergency Management said that the Edenville and Sanford dams "are structurally sound but can no longer control or contain the amount of water flowing through the spill gates." The county is working with the hydroelectric power plant Boyce Hydro to assess the dams.

"At this point, the water is still rising from all of the rainfall we received over the last couple of days and it will continue to do so throughout the day," the Midland County Central Dispatch Authority said Tuesday.

A flood warning remains in effect for the Tittabawassee, from Midland downstream to Saginaw, and the forecast does not show relief for Midland.